Settlements
- Approximately 90% of all private antitrust cases are settled prior to the final judicial decision
- A simple risk calculation of the expected outcome of the case justifies this large proportion of settlements
- We can show the probability of a settlement rests on three things:
- Damages
- Differences between the defendant’s and plaintiff’s view on the success of the case
- Cost of the case
Expected return
- Suppose the antitrust violation caused damage \(D\) and the plaintiff believes they can win the case with probability \(\theta_p\)
- A successful plaintiff recovers treble damages plus the cost of the suit \(C_p\)
- An unsuccessful plaintiff recovers no damages and must pay the cost of the suit
- We can calculate the plaintiff’s expected return (E(R)) from going to court:
\[ E[R]=\theta_p(3D) + (1-\theta_p)(-C_p) \]
- The defendant must always pay their costs \(C_d\) and believes they will lose the case with probability \(\theta_d\)
- We can calculate the defendant’s expected loss (E[L))
\[ \begin{aligned} E[L]&=\theta_d(3D+C_p+C_d)+(1-\theta_d)C_d \\ &=\theta_d(3D+C_p)+C_d \end{aligned} \]
When will a settlement occur?
- We can think of the suit as a risky asset owned by the plaintiff (with a value equal to the expected return E[R]) and owed by the defendant (with a value equal to the expected loss E[L])
- If the defendant values the ‘asset’ more than the plaintiff, they will attempt to ‘buy’ it (i.e., settle the lawsuit)
- Mathematically, a settlement occurs when the expected loss to the defendant exceeds the expected return to the plaintiff:
\[ \begin{aligned} E[L]&>E[R]\\ \theta_d(3D+C_p)+C_d &> \theta_p(3D)-(1-\theta_p)C_p \end{aligned} \]
\[ (\theta_d-\theta_p)3D + (\theta_d-\theta_p)C_p+(C_d+C_p) > 0 \]
- Intuitively, a settlement occurs if it is cheaper for the defendant to pay everything the plaintiff expects to win, relative to the cost of going to court
- If the defendant believes the plaintiff has a higher chance of winning, relative to the plaintiff’s own belief they will win (i.e. \(\theta_d\) > \(\theta_p\)), then there will always be a settlement
Example 1
Imagine that Channel 5, a small media company, files a lawsuit against Waystar Royco, a media conglomerate accused of predatory business practices.
- Channel 5 believes their probability of winning the lawsuit is 40% where they will pay \(C_p = \$30,000\) in costs.
- Waystar Royco believes their probability of losing the lawsuit is 50% where their costs total to \(C_d = \$50,000\)
- If the estimated damages are D = $100,000 will a settlement occur?
Plaintiff’s expected return
\[ E[R] = 0.4(3\cdot 100,000)+(1-0.4)(-30,000) = 102,000 \]
Defendant’s expected loss
\[ E[L]=0.5(3\cdot 100,000+30,000+50,000)+(1-0.5)50,000 = 215,000 \]
\(E[L]>E[R]\) , settlement will occur
Example 2
Plaintiff’s expected return
\[ E[R]=0.4(3\cdot 100,000)-(1-0.4)30,000 = 102,000 \]
Defendant’s expected loss
\[ E[L]=0.1(3\cdot100,000 + 30,000+50,000)+(1-0.1)50,000 = 83,000 \]
Since \(E[L]<E[R]\), settlement will not occur
Summary of steps to solving settlement problems
- Calculate the expected return from a lawsuit for the plaintiff (remember that, if they win, they receive triple the amount of damages)
- Calculate the expected loss from a lawsuit for the defendant (remember that they’re required to pay their costs even if they win the case)
- Compare the two values. If the expected loss is greater than the expected return, the defendant will “buy” the suit and a settlement will occur.
Instruments of Discovery
- Before the trial begins, both sides should have access to the same information through the process of fact discovery
- Documents: any records that have some bearing on the case
- Interrogatory answers: written responses to specific questions posed before the trial
- Depositions: sworn testimonies (audio or video recorded) of anyone with relevant information (e.g. witnesses)