Sherman Antitrust Act
Trusts were finally limited by the Sherman Act of 1890
- Main provisions of the Sherman Act are contained in the first two sections:
- Section 1: forming a trust, or attempting to form a trust between firms is illegal
- Section 2: forming or attempting to form a monopoly is illegal
Taken together, this outlawed specific firm behavior
- Cartels were explicitly banned
- Mergers that increased efficiency were allowed, while mergers that increased market power were not – hence, a natural monopoly does not violate the Sherman Act
Issues with the Sherman Act
- The Sherman Act is (intentionally?) vague
- What constitutes a contract or conspiracy “in restraint of trade”?
- How can one determine if a firm is acting as a monopoly or attempting to monopolize
- When is it a conspiracy?
- Regulators face a difficult job of detecting and punishing monopolistic behavior
- Are firms exhibiting non-competitive activities, or are they just more efficient than their competition?
- Is the monopoly using their market power to discourage competition, or are they merely a natural monopoly?
- Will regulation disincentivize competition?
Penalties and Sanctions
- Enforcing the Sherman Act was difficult
- Enforcement was deferred to the courts
- They created guidelines for determining whether firms are in violation of the act
- Initially, the penalty for a violation was a maximum of $100M for firms for each offense, and up to 10 years in prison and $1M in fines for individuals for each offense
- What if a firm can make an extra $100M by acting as a monopoly?
- In order to incentivize legal firm behavior, Congress passed the Criminal Fines Improvement Act, allowing regulators to fine offenders up to twice the value of the firm’s pecuniary gains
- However, firms know that they will not always be caught…
Sanctions Example
- Let’s consider an example where a firm is trying to decide whether to act competitively or behave as a monopoly
- Suppose that if a firm acts as a monopoly, it can earn $60M in profit
- The firm believes there is a 40% chance that it will get caught (violating the Sherman Act)
- If found guilty, the firm will have to pay $3M in legal fees and the CEO will go to jail for 10 years, which she values at $12M
- What is the firm’s expected profit by acting as a monopoly?
\[ \begin{aligned} E(\Pi) &=P(\text{not caught})\cdot \Pi_{monopoly} + P(\text{caught})\cdot (\Pi_{monopoly}-\text{fines})\\ &=0.6(\$60\text{m}) + 0.4(\$60\text{m}-\$120\text{m} - \$3\text{m} - \$12\text{m}) \\ &=\$36\text{m} - \$30\text{m} \\ &=\$6\text{m} \end{aligned} \]
- Notice the firm expects to make more profit if they act as a monopolist, relative to competitively (zero profit condition)
- Recall that firms are self-interested and profit maximizing → The firm will illegally act as a monopoly
- In this case the conduct is unlikely to be deterred
- The intent of the Sherman Act was to deter monopoly behavior, not punish it
Legislative Intent of the Sherman Act
- Diving deeper into the intent of the Sherman Act, we will look at two influential interpretations:
- Robert Bork: The intent of the Sherman Act was to promote consumer welfare through allocative efficiency
- Robert Lande: The intent of the Sherman Act was to prevent firms with market power from unfairly transferring wealth from consumers to themselves
Bork Interpretation
- Sherman’s main concern was with behavior that prevents “full and free competition” and raises prices for consumers
- Bork discussed the closure of fish, deli, and produce markets in favor of supermarkets
- Supermarkets would not be a violation of the Sherman Act, since although supermarkets may force out smaller, specialized markets, they increase efficiency in a way that benefits consumers (i.e. cost savings can, in theory, be passed on to consumers)
Lande Interpretation
- Lande believed the intent of the Sherman Act was to prevent unfair wealth transfers from consumers to producers
- As in, the writers of the act did not care about economic efficiency but rather wanted a law that favored consumers over producers.
- This interpretation argues that, in addition to preventing unfair wealth transfers, Congress wanted to limit the social and political power of large firms.
Consequences of Varying Interpretations
- A firm monopolizes a market through unfair predatory business practicies, both Borke and Lande believed the firm activity violated the Sherman Act
- This is not always the case
- Consider a profit maximizing natural monopoly
- Recall that natural monopolies occur because they are more efficient than many smaller, competitive firms
- Due to the market power of monopoly, the firm can price as a monopolist and extract more wealth from consumers (relative to the competitive alternative)
- Bork believed this natural monopoly is legal, since it’s more efficient than competition
- Lande believed this natural monopoly is illegal, since it’s still transferring wealth from consumers to the firm
Early Enforcement
Early enforcement: Peckham Rule
- Between 1897-1899, Supreme Court Justice Rufus Peckham wrote five opinions in antitrust cases. In the course of these decisions emerged the Peckham Rule in antitrust cases
- The rule stated that any business practices designed to restrict output were illegal.
- This rule is consistent with legislative aim of promoting consumer welfare.
Early enforcement: Issues
- Early enforcement of the Sherman Act had many problems
- Many businesses did not know if they were at risk of prosecution due to the vagueness of the law
- Enforcement was often left to the judge’s discretion
- Firms could work around the Sherman Act by finding ways to mask anticompetitive behavior/effects.
- The Sherman Act was almost immediately identified as flawed
- Teddy Roosevelt who read the Sherman Act to forbid all combinations regardless of their economic effect opposed the legislation.
- Roosevelt proposed his own solution:
- Create a list of all impermissible business practices
- Give a license to businesses to do anything not on the list
Rule of Reason
- The Rule of Reason is a heuristic for enforcing the Sherman Act and comes from the case of Standard Oil Co. v. United States (1911)
- Every monopolization case under the Sherman Act must be viewed independently on its own merit
- Contracts or conduct to exclude rival firms was illegal; however, being a monopoly was not illegal per se
- Affirmed the remedy of breaking up the firm into 34 parts
- Despite the new heuristic for determining antitrust, the Sherman Act was still criticized
- Viewed as giving too much power to judges
- Viewed as an attempt at fixing monopolization, as opposed to preventing it from occurring